Picture of author.

Thomas C. Schelling (1921–2016)

Author of The Strategy of Conflict

14+ Works 1,518 Members 8 Reviews 1 Favorited

About the Author

Thomas Crombie Schelling was born in Oakland, California on April 14, 1921. He received a bachelor's degree in economics from the University of California, Berkeley in 1944. After working as an analyst for the federal Bureau of the Budget, he attended Harvard University. He spent two years in show more Denmark and France as an economist for the Economic Cooperation Administration. In 1950, he joined the White House staff of the foreign policy adviser to President Harry S. Truman. In 1951, he received his doctorate from Harvard and published his first book, National Income Behavior: An Introduction to Algebraic Analysis. He taught economics at Yale University, Harvard University, and the University of Maryland's Department of Economics and School of Public Policy before retiring in 2003. He wrote several books during his lifetime including International Economics, The Strategy of Conflict, Strategy and Arms Control written with Morton H. Halperin, Arms and Influence, Micromotives and Macrobehavior, Choice and Consequence, and Strategies of Commitment. In 2005, he and Robert J. Aumann received the Nobel Prize in economic science for "having enhanced our understanding of conflict and cooperation through game-theory analysis." He died on December 13, 2016 at the age of 95. (Bowker Author Biography) show less
Image credit: Photo by user Hessam Armandehi / Wikimedia Commons.

Series

Works by Thomas C. Schelling

Associated Works

Power and Struggle (1973) — Introduction — 157 copies
Methods of Nonviolent Action (1973) — Introduction — 127 copies
The Dynamics of Nonviolent Action (1974) — Introduction — 118 copies
Pearl Harbor: Warning and Decision (1962) — Foreword — 115 copies
The Politics of Nonviolent Action [3-volume set] (1973) — Introduction — 99 copies
On Escalation: Metaphors and Scenarios (1965) — Introduction — 62 copies
Global Problems, Smart Solutions: Costs and Benefits (2013) — Contributor — 3 copies

Tagged

Common Knowledge

Members

Reviews

there are some interesting situations where seemingly simple individual behaviors aggregate to surprising and potentially disappointing collective results: hockey players given an individual choice will opt for no helmet, making themselves collectively worse off and begging for league-mandated helmets; homeowners with a slight preference to live near people who look like themselves will induce stark segregation that shocks their own consciences. if these examples are familiar it is because this book introduced them.

the style of reasoning used in this book is now so familiar that it was briefly a meme: you could say schelling was the original "it's time for some game theory" guy. but that would be unfair, i think: the meme is mocking a top-down, overly theoretic way of forcing the facts into speculative theories. in this book schelling is sensitive to the facts of concrete situations, working in a bottom-up fashion that starts with humdrum examples taken from life, adding more detailed observations to the model until he brings it to the breaking point.

one pleasure of the book is seeing a systematic thinker at work: when schelling is done modeling a situation, he begins turning the parameter dials to see what other interesting outcomes he can get in theory and considering what concrete situations they might describe. when he's exhausted those possibilities, he lays the various models out and organizes them into logical schema. even there he does not stop, but instead ponders the nature of these schema, their limitations, their general properties: where do these simple accounting identities come from? what are the limits of their application? what kinds are there for closed and open systems? why do they seem obvious only after we have used them for a time?

schelling has a unique mind and i may need to dip into his other books.
… (more)
 
Flagged
leeinaustin | 4 other reviews | May 17, 2021 |
A weak 4 but this is a classic. His Nobel speech afterword really ties a lot together and hammers home the importance of nuclear weapons as a tool of influence, rather than an actual weapon to be used. Some weird moments of pro-peaceful nuclear energy advocacy?
 
Flagged
goliathonline | Jul 7, 2020 |
This is one of the most important books on Game Theory, and also, thankfully, one of the more accessible (certainly much more so than von Neumann's and Morgenstern's book).

His main theses are that not all games are zero-sum. That is, they are 'variable-sum', or dependent upon the strategies used. Not all actors are apparently rational, and some may act on seemingly irrational behavior in order to alter their opponent's responses. On the individual level, this could be the abusive lover threatening to kill themselves in order to keep you obedient to them. On the international level, this could be the North Koreans lobbing more missiles into the ocean to get more food. Decisions are interdependent upon the other's decisions.

Perceptions are also a vital component of decision making. Limiting information available to the opponent, or restricting their choices by other means, is a way to appropriately modify your own action. Strategy is not only a way of dealing with force, but also potential force.

In cooperative games, coordination is necessary. If communication is possible, then it would be best to aim for some point that you know that the other target might think of as being a valuable and important meeting point. These are now referred to as 'focal points', or, more recently, 'Schelling points'.

The idea of 'deterrence' has to have two necessary components: a conflict, and a common interest. Bargaining is a means by which both actors can find ways to benefit, but this becomes more difficult in areas of more open conflict, as the means of communication may become impeded. Therefore, a tacit communication or tacit bargaining - a scale of responses with which one communicates, up to and including armed force.

Some of these points may seem obvious now, fifty years later, but they seem even more important only because of how often they are overlooked. Schelling is important not entirely because of his mathematical analysis, but because how he also encompasses the human element in decision-making. The Cuban Missile Crisis, the ultimate 'game' of brinksmanship, coordination, and negotiation, only occurred two years after this book was published. Valuable reading for economists, politicians, and anybody who wants more than a passing knowledge of these games we play.
… (more)
 
Flagged
HadriantheBlind | Mar 30, 2013 |

Lists

Awards

You May Also Like

Associated Authors

Statistics

Works
14
Also by
8
Members
1,518
Popularity
#16,945
Rating
4.0
Reviews
8
ISBNs
44
Languages
5
Favorited
1

Charts & Graphs